 |  | 

October 2023
One of the most important things I didn't understand about the world
+when I was a child is the degree to which the returns for performance
+are superlinear.
Teachers and coaches implicitly told us the returns were linear.
+"You get out," I heard a thousand times, "what you put in." They
+meant well, but this is rarely true. If your product is only half
+as good as your competitor's, you don't get half as many customers.
+You get no customers, and you go out of business.
It's obviously true that the returns for performance are superlinear
+in business. Some think this is a flaw of capitalism, and that if
+we changed the rules it would stop being true. But superlinear
+returns for performance are a feature of the world, not an artifact
+of rules we've invented. We see the same pattern in fame, power,
+military victories, knowledge, and even benefit to humanity. In all
+of these, the rich get richer.
+[1]
You can't understand the world without understanding the concept
+of superlinear returns. And if you're ambitious you definitely
+should, because this will be the wave you surf on.
It may seem as if there are a lot of different situations with
+superlinear returns, but as far as I can tell they reduce to two
+fundamental causes: exponential growth and thresholds.
The most obvious case of superlinear returns is when you're working
+on something that grows exponentially. For example, growing bacterial
+cultures. When they grow at all, they grow exponentially. But they're
+tricky to grow. Which means the difference in outcome between someone
+who's adept at it and someone who's not is very great.
Startups can also grow exponentially, and we see the same pattern
+there. Some manage to achieve high growth rates. Most don't. And
+as a result you get qualitatively different outcomes: the companies
+with high growth rates tend to become immensely valuable, while the
+ones with lower growth rates may not even survive.
Y Combinator encourages founders to focus on growth rate rather
+than absolute numbers. It prevents them from being discouraged early
+on, when the absolute numbers are still low. It also helps them
+decide what to focus on: you can use growth rate as a compass to
+tell you how to evolve the company. But the main advantage is that
+by focusing on growth rate you tend to get something that grows
+exponentially.
YC doesn't explicitly tell founders that with growth rate "you get
+out what you put in," but it's not far from the truth. And if growth
+rate were proportional to performance, then the reward for performance
+p over time t would be proportional to pt.
Even after decades of thinking about this, I find that sentence
+startling.
Whenever how well you do depends on how well you've done, you'll
+get exponential growth. But neither our DNA nor our customs prepare
+us for it. No one finds exponential growth natural; every child is
+surprised, the first time they hear it, by the story of the man who
+asks the king for a single grain of rice the first day and double
+the amount each successive day.
What we don't understand naturally we develop customs to deal with,
+but we don't have many customs about exponential growth either,
+because there have been so few instances of it in human history.
+In principle herding should have been one: the more animals you
+had, the more offspring they'd have. But in practice grazing land
+was the limiting factor, and there was no plan for growing that
+exponentially.
Or more precisely, no generally applicable plan. There was a way
+to grow one's territory exponentially: by conquest. The more territory
+you control, the more powerful your army becomes, and the easier
+it is to conquer new territory. This is why history is full of
+empires. But so few people created or ran empires that their
+experiences didn't affect customs very much. The emperor was a
+remote and terrifying figure, not a source of lessons one could use
+in one's own life.
The most common case of exponential growth in preindustrial times
+was probably scholarship. The more you know, the easier it is to
+learn new things. The result, then as now, was that some people
+were startlingly more knowledgeable than the rest about certain
+topics. But this didn't affect customs much either. Although empires
+of ideas can overlap and there can thus be far more emperors, in
+preindustrial times this type of empire had little practical effect.
+[2]
That has changed in the last few centuries. Now the emperors of
+ideas can design bombs that defeat the emperors of territory. But
+this phenomenon is still so new that we haven't fully assimilated
+it. Few even of the participants realize they're benefitting from
+exponential growth or ask what they can learn from other instances
+of it.
The other source of superlinear returns is embodied in the expression
+"winner take all." In a sports match the relationship between
+performance and return is a step function: the winning team gets
+one win whether they do much better or just slightly better.
+[3]
The source of the step function is not competition per se, however.
+It's that there are thresholds in the outcome. You don't need
+competition to get those. There can be thresholds in situations
+where you're the only participant, like proving a theorem or hitting
+a target.
It's remarkable how often a situation with one source of superlinear
+returns also has the other. Crossing thresholds leads to exponential
+growth: the winning side in a battle usually suffers less damage,
+which makes them more likely to win in the future. And exponential
+growth helps you cross thresholds: in a market with network effects,
+a company that grows fast enough can shut out potential competitors.
Fame is an interesting example of a phenomenon that combines both
+sources of superlinear returns. Fame grows exponentially because
+existing fans bring you new ones. But the fundamental reason it's
+so concentrated is thresholds: there's only so much room on the
+A-list in the average person's head.
The most important case combining both sources of superlinear returns
+may be learning. Knowledge grows exponentially, but there are also
+thresholds in it. Learning to ride a bicycle, for example. Some of
+these thresholds are akin to machine tools: once you learn to read,
+you're able to learn anything else much faster. But the most important
+thresholds of all are those representing new discoveries. Knowledge
+seems to be fractal in the sense that if you push hard at the
+boundary of one area of knowledge, you sometimes discover a whole
+new field. And if you do, you get first crack at all the new
+discoveries to be made in it. Newton did this, and so did Durer and
+Darwin.
+Are there general rules for finding situations with superlinear
+returns? The most obvious one is to seek work that compounds.
There are two ways work can compound. It can compound directly, in
+the sense that doing well in one cycle causes you to do better in
+the next. That happens for example when you're building infrastructure,
+or growing an audience or brand. Or work can compound by teaching
+you, since learning compounds. This second case is an interesting
+one because you may feel you're doing badly as it's happening. You
+may be failing to achieve your immediate goal. But if you're learning
+a lot, then you're getting exponential growth nonetheless.
This is one reason Silicon Valley is so tolerant of failure. People
+in Silicon Valley aren't blindly tolerant of failure. They'll only
+continue to bet on you if you're learning from your failures. But
+if you are, you are in fact a good bet: maybe your company didn't
+grow the way you wanted, but you yourself have, and that should
+yield results eventually.
Indeed, the forms of exponential growth that don't consist of
+learning are so often intermixed with it that we should probably
+treat this as the rule rather than the exception. Which yields
+another heuristic: always be learning. If you're not learning,
+you're probably not on a path that leads to superlinear returns.
But don't overoptimize what you're learning. Don't limit yourself
+to learning things that are already known to be valuable. You're
+learning; you don't know for sure yet what's going to be valuable,
+and if you're too strict you'll lop off the outliers.
What about step functions? Are there also useful heuristics of the
+form "seek thresholds" or "seek competition?" Here the situation
+is trickier. The existence of a threshold doesn't guarantee the
+game will be worth playing. If you play a round of Russian roulette,
+you'll be in a situation with a threshold, certainly, but in the
+best case you're no better off. "Seek competition" is similarly
+useless; what if the prize isn't worth competing for? Sufficiently
+fast exponential growth guarantees both the shape and magnitude of
+the return curve — because something that grows fast enough will
+grow big even if it's trivially small at first — but thresholds
+only guarantee the shape.
+[4]
A principle for taking advantage of thresholds has to include a
+test to ensure the game is worth playing. Here's one that does: if
+you come across something that's mediocre yet still popular, it
+could be a good idea to replace it. For example, if a company makes
+a product that people dislike yet still buy, then presumably they'd
+buy a better alternative if you made one.
+[5]
It would be great if there were a way to find promising intellectual
+thresholds. Is there a way to tell which questions have whole new
+fields beyond them? I doubt we could ever predict this with certainty,
+but the prize is so valuable that it would be useful to have
+predictors that were even a little better than random, and there's
+hope of finding those. We can to some degree predict when a research
+problem isn't likely to lead to new discoveries: when it seems
+legit but boring. Whereas the kind that do lead to new discoveries
+tend to seem very mystifying, but perhaps unimportant. (If they
+were mystifying and obviously important, they'd be famous open
+questions with lots of people already working on them.) So one
+heuristic here is to be driven by curiosity rather than careerism
+— to give free rein to your curiosity instead of working on what
+you're supposed to.
+The prospect of superlinear returns for performance is an exciting
+one for the ambitious. And there's good news in this department:
+this territory is expanding in both directions. There are more types
+of work in which you can get superlinear returns, and the returns
+themselves are growing.
There are two reasons for this, though they're so closely intertwined
+that they're more like one and a half: progress in technology, and
+the decreasing importance of organizations.
Fifty years ago it used to be much more necessary to be part of an
+organization to work on ambitious projects. It was the only way to
+get the resources you needed, the only way to have colleagues, and
+the only way to get distribution. So in 1970 your prestige was in
+most cases the prestige of the organization you belonged to. And
+prestige was an accurate predictor, because if you weren't part of
+an organization, you weren't likely to achieve much. There were a
+handful of exceptions, most notably artists and writers, who worked
+alone using inexpensive tools and had their own brands. But even
+they were at the mercy of organizations for reaching audiences.
+[6]
A world dominated by organizations damped variation in the returns
+for performance. But this world has eroded significantly just in
+my lifetime. Now a lot more people can have the freedom that artists
+and writers had in the 20th century. There are lots of ambitious
+projects that don't require much initial funding, and lots of new
+ways to learn, make money, find colleagues, and reach audiences.
There's still plenty of the old world left, but the rate of change
+has been dramatic by historical standards. Especially considering
+what's at stake. It's hard to imagine a more fundamental change
+than one in the returns for performance.
Without the damping effect of institutions, there will be more
+variation in outcomes. Which doesn't imply everyone will be better
+off: people who do well will do even better, but those who do badly
+will do worse. That's an important point to bear in mind. Exposing
+oneself to superlinear returns is not for everyone. Most people
+will be better off as part of the pool. So who should shoot for
+superlinear returns? Ambitious people of two types: those who know
+they're so good that they'll be net ahead in a world with higher
+variation, and those, particularly the young, who can afford to
+risk trying it to find out.
+[7]
The switch away from institutions won't simply be an exodus of their
+current inhabitants. Many of the new winners will be people they'd
+never have let in. So the resulting democratization of opportunity
+will be both greater and more authentic than any tame intramural
+version the institutions themselves might have cooked up.
+Not everyone is happy about this great unlocking of ambition. It
+threatens some vested interests and contradicts some ideologies. [8]
+But if you're an ambitious individual it's good news for you.
+How should you take advantage of it?
The most obvious way to take advantage of superlinear returns for
+performance is by doing exceptionally good work. At the far end of
+the curve, incremental effort is a bargain. All the more so because
+there's less competition at the far end — and not just for the
+obvious reason that it's hard to do something exceptionally well,
+but also because people find the prospect so intimidating that few
+even try. Which means it's not just a bargain to do exceptional
+work, but a bargain even to try to.
There are many variables that affect how good your work is, and if
+you want to be an outlier you need to get nearly all of them right.
+For example, to do something exceptionally well, you have to be
+interested in it. Mere diligence is not enough. So in a world with
+superlinear returns, it's even more valuable to know what you're
+interested in, and to find ways to work on it.
+[9]
+It will also be
+important to choose work that suits your circumstances. For example,
+if there's a kind of work that inherently requires a huge expenditure
+of time and energy, it will be increasingly valuable to do it when
+you're young and don't yet have children.
There's a surprising amount of technique to doing great work.
+It's not just a matter of trying hard. I'm going to take a shot
+giving a recipe in one paragraph.
Choose work you have a natural aptitude for and a deep interest in.
+Develop a habit of working on your own projects; it doesn't matter
+what they are so long as you find them excitingly ambitious. Work
+as hard as you can without burning out, and this will eventually
+bring you to one of the frontiers of knowledge. These look smooth
+from a distance, but up close they're full of gaps. Notice and
+explore such gaps, and if you're lucky one will expand into a whole
+new field. Take as much risk as you can afford; if you're not failing
+occasionally you're probably being too conservative. Seek out the
+best colleagues. Develop good taste and learn from the best examples.
+Be honest, especially with yourself. Exercise and eat and sleep
+well and avoid the more dangerous drugs. When in doubt, follow your
+curiosity. It never lies, and it knows more than you do about what's
+worth paying attention to.
+[10]
And there is of course one other thing you need: to be lucky. Luck
+is always a factor, but it's even more of a factor when you're
+working on your own rather than as part of an organization. And
+though there are some valid aphorisms about luck being where
+preparedness meets opportunity and so on, there's also a component
+of true chance that you can't do anything about. The solution is
+to take multiple shots. Which is another reason to start taking
+risks early.
+The best example of a field with superlinear returns is probably
+science. It has exponential growth, in the form of learning, combined
+with thresholds at the extreme edge of performance — literally at
+the limits of knowledge.
The result has been a level of inequality in scientific discovery
+that makes the wealth inequality of even the most stratified societies
+seem mild by comparison. Newton's discoveries were arguably greater
+than all his contemporaries' combined.
+[11]
This point may seem obvious, but it might be just as well to spell
+it out. Superlinear returns imply inequality. The steeper the return
+curve, the greater the variation in outcomes.
In fact, the correlation between superlinear returns and inequality
+is so strong that it yields another heuristic for finding work of
+this type: look for fields where a few big winners outperform
+everyone else. A kind of work where everyone does about the same
+is unlikely to be one with superlinear returns.
What are fields where a few big winners outperform everyone else?
+Here are some obvious ones: sports, politics, art, music, acting,
+directing, writing, math, science, starting companies, and investing.
+In sports the phenomenon is due to externally imposed thresholds;
+you only need to be a few percent faster to win every race. In
+politics, power grows much as it did in the days of emperors. And
+in some of the other fields (including politics) success is driven
+largely by fame, which has its own source of superlinear growth.
+But when we exclude sports and politics and the effects of fame, a
+remarkable pattern emerges: the remaining list is exactly the same
+as the list of fields where you have to be independent-minded to
+succeed — where your ideas have to be not just correct, but novel
+as well.
+[12]
This is obviously the case in science. You can't publish papers
+saying things that other people have already said. But it's just
+as true in investing, for example. It's only useful to believe that
+a company will do well if most other investors don't; if everyone
+else thinks the company will do well, then its stock price will
+already reflect that, and there's no room to make money.
What else can we learn from these fields? In all of them you have
+to put in the initial effort. Superlinear returns seem small at
+first. At this rate, you find yourself thinking, I'll never get
+anywhere. But because the reward curve rises so steeply at the far
+end, it's worth taking extraordinary measures to get there.
In the startup world, the name for this principle is "do things
+that don't scale." If you pay a ridiculous amount of attention to
+your tiny initial set of customers, ideally you'll kick off exponential
+growth by word of mouth. But this same principle applies to anything
+that grows exponentially. Learning, for example. When you first
+start learning something, you feel lost. But it's worth making the
+initial effort to get a toehold, because the more you learn, the
+easier it will get.
There's another more subtle lesson in the list of fields with
+superlinear returns: not to equate work with a job. For most of the
+20th century the two were identical for nearly everyone, and as a
+result we've inherited a custom that equates productivity with
+having a job. Even now to most people the phrase "your work" means
+their job. But to a writer or artist or scientist it means whatever
+they're currently studying or creating. For someone like that, their
+work is something they carry with them from job to job, if they
+have jobs at all. It may be done for an employer, but it's part of
+their portfolio.
+It's an intimidating prospect to enter a field where a few big
+winners outperform everyone else. Some people do this deliberately,
+but you don't need to. If you have sufficient natural ability and
+you follow your curiosity sufficiently far, you'll end up in one.
+Your curiosity won't let you be interested in boring questions, and
+interesting questions tend to create fields with superlinear returns
+if they're not already part of one.
The territory of superlinear returns is by no means static. Indeed,
+the most extreme returns come from expanding it. So while both
+ambition and curiosity can get you into this territory, curiosity
+may be the more powerful of the two. Ambition tends to make you
+climb existing peaks, but if you stick close enough to an interesting
+enough question, it may grow into a mountain beneath you.
Notes
There's a limit to how sharply you can distinguish between effort,
+performance, and return, because they're not sharply distinguished
+in fact. What counts as return to one person might be performance
+to another. But though the borders of these concepts are blurry,
+they're not meaningless. I've tried to write about them as precisely
+as I could without crossing into error.
[1]
+Evolution itself is probably the most pervasive example of
+superlinear returns for performance. But this is hard for us to
+empathize with because we're not the recipients; we're the returns.
[2]
+Knowledge did of course have a practical effect before the
+Industrial Revolution. The development of agriculture changed human
+life completely. But this kind of change was the result of broad,
+gradual improvements in technique, not the discoveries of a few
+exceptionally learned people.
[3]
+It's not mathematically correct to describe a step function as
+superlinear, but a step function starting from zero works like a
+superlinear function when it describes the reward curve for effort
+by a rational actor. If it starts at zero then the part before the
+step is below any linearly increasing return, and the part after
+the step must be above the necessary return at that point or no one
+would bother.
[4]
+Seeking competition could be a good heuristic in the sense that
+some people find it motivating. It's also somewhat of a guide to
+promising problems, because it's a sign that other people find them
+promising. But it's a very imperfect sign: often there's a clamoring
+crowd chasing some problem, and they all end up being trumped by
+someone quietly working on another one.
[5]
+Not always, though. You have to be careful with this rule. When
+something is popular despite being mediocre, there's often a hidden
+reason why. Perhaps monopoly or regulation make it hard to compete.
+Perhaps customers have bad taste or have broken procedures for
+deciding what to buy. There are huge swathes of mediocre things
+that exist for such reasons.
[6]
+In my twenties I wanted to be an artist
+and even went to art
+school to study painting. Mostly because I liked art, but a nontrivial
+part of my motivation came from the fact that artists seemed least
+at the mercy of organizations.
[7]
+In principle everyone is getting superlinear returns. Learning
+compounds, and everyone learns in the course of their life. But in
+practice few push this kind of everyday learning to the point where
+the return curve gets really steep.
[8]
+It's unclear exactly what advocates of "equity" mean by it.
+They seem to disagree among themselves. But whatever they mean is
+probably at odds with a world in which institutions have less power
+to control outcomes, and a handful of outliers do much better than
+everyone else.
It may seem like bad luck for this concept that it arose at just
+the moment when the world was shifting in the opposite direction,
+but I don't think this was a coincidence. I think one reason it
+arose now is because its adherents feel threatened by rapidly
+increasing variation in performance.
[9]
+Corollary: Parents who pressure their kids to work on something
+prestigious, like medicine, even though they have no interest in
+it, will be hosing them even more than they have in the past.
[10]
+The original version of this paragraph was the first draft of
+"How to Do Great Work."
+As soon as I wrote it I realized it was a more important topic than superlinear
+returns, so I paused the present essay to expand this paragraph into its
+own. Practically nothing remains of the original version, because
+after I finished "How to Do Great Work" I rewrote it based on that.
[11]
+Before the Industrial Revolution, people who got rich usually
+did it like emperors: capturing some resource made them more powerful
+and enabled them to capture more. Now it can be done like a scientist,
+by discovering or building something uniquely valuable. Most people
+who get rich use a mix of the old and the new ways, but in the most
+advanced economies the ratio has shifted dramatically toward discovery
+just in the last half century.
[12]
+It's not surprising that conventional-minded people would
+dislike inequality if independent-mindedness is one of the biggest
+drivers of it. But it's not simply that they don't want anyone to
+have what they can't. The conventional-minded literally can't imagine
+what it's like to have novel ideas. So the whole phenomenon of great
+variation in performance seems unnatural to them, and when they
+encounter it they assume it must be due to cheating or to some
+malign external influence.
Thanks
+to Trevor Blackwell, Patrick Collusion, Tyler Cowen,
+Jessica Livingston, Harj Taggar, and Garry Tan for reading drafts
+of this.
|
|